Saturday, September 24, 2011

More on Bryan Caplan, ethnic diversity and the size of government.

Bryan Caplan has now responded to my post arguing that open borders will expand the welfare state. The discussion continues below:

1. Caplan almost entirely relies on Alesina, Glaser and Sacerdote (2001). The paper shows that globally, ethnic fractionalization correlates negatively with social expenditure. I have however shown that this result does not hold for rich OECD countries.

The Alesina et al. paper paper uses “Social expenditure”, a subcategory of the welfare state, which includes transfers but not things like public health care. Social expenditure only constitutes about 40% of total government spending in the U.S. The correct measure of the size of the welfare state is total expenditure, not just one subcategory of spending. I therefore used total public expenditure in my last post. But let’s not let this details distract us.

It turns out that for rich OECD countries, there is no statistically significant relationship with the degree of ethnic fractionalization even if we use OECD “social expenditure” data just as Alesina et al. did. I look at 1990-2000, to correspond with the years the fragmentation data was calculated.


It turns out Alesinia et al. relationship between diversity and a small welfare state is entirely driven by third world countries. But Caplan is discussing immigration to the west; not how tribal fragmentation impacts policy in Africa.

Caplan argues: “instead of throwing away most of the data and variation, it's better to keep the data and add control variables.“

Incorrect. Since we are specifically discussing immigration to the west, we need to throw away the variation that comes from poor African and Latin American countries. Adding dummies does not solve this (though a combination of dummies and interaction variables might have). Even with a regional dummy, the large number of African and Latin countries can drive the results, even when there is no relationship within rich OECD countries.

When I restrict the analyses to rich nations, it turns out that the relationship between diversity and small government does not hold. The results in the paper Caplan builds his entire case on are driven by how fragmentation effects third world countries.

It is logically flawed to have African data generate a relationship, and proceed to argue (as Caplan does) that this proves that more diversity will reduce the size of government in the United States, even though we know the relationship doesn’t hold in rich countries.

Alesina et al. have another misleading graph, which Caplan also relies heavily on. This shows that in the U.S, states with a high percentage of African Americans have lower welfare benefits per welfare recipient. But expenditure is not measured by benefits per recipient; it is measured by the benefit per recipient times the number of recipients. States with more minorities have more welfare recipients. You have to look at both effects, which Alesinas paper neglects to do. This is important, as empirically, it appears that the second effect dominates the first, so that the size of government is bigger in more diverse states (though it is not unproblematic to compare U.S states in this way).

I am glad that Caplan now acknowledges that we need to take into account the effect of demography on the number of welfare recipients, not only welfare per recipient. He has written about the Alesina paper numerous times, and never once pointed out that Alesina graph is only half the story. I might have pointed out this problem to him and his readers if I were not banned from his blog.

Caplan also claims that “AGS's graphs and regressions are better”.

Why? I am using the exact same ethnic fractionalization data that they use (since I downloaded it from their appendix) and standard social expenditure data from the OECD just like they did. The main difference is that I look at rich OECD democracies, since we are discussing policy in those rich countries, and since there are many obvious reasons to believe the mechanisms are not the same as in the third world.

What I do is very similar, so it is hard to escape the conclusion that Caplans objection are not methodological. He just prefers the old result because that produces his preferred ideological outcome.

Aside from all of this, I have to stress that the causal interpretation of the Alesina et. al story which Caplan has made repeatedly is problematic, since the authors only report correlations. There are plenty of differences between the United States and Scandinavia besides how ethnically fractured they are. There are plenty of differences between New England and the South besides the share of African Americans.

2. I write that if ethnic diversity increases poverty and social problems, the left gets more votes, since this increases the demand for government policies to fix the problems. Caplan writes that this is “theoretically confused”. He further writes “the entire political spectrum is indeed irrational, and habitually demands government intervention for no good reason”. (Caplan thinks there is no good reason because according to him poverty in rich countries is merely relative).

I see two problems with this assertion. First, I believe that Caplan is projecting his own atypical preferences to everyone else. People on average have an aversion to relative poverty. This is a preference, not something you can simply dismiss as “irrational”.

Second, more importantly, he is mixing a positive and normative debate. Even if you think that the tendency of voters to demand public intervention as a result of larger social problems of relative poverty is “irrational” or otherwise immoral or confused, this tendency is an objective fact of political reality, not something that you can assume away because you disagree with it.

3. Caplan writes:

“Sanandaji also ignores the possibility that immigrants vote “overwhelmingly for the left” primarily because right-wing parties treat them with such hostility. “

There is no evidence for this claim.

Hispanics did not vote for consistent amnesty supporter John McCain. By no reasonable definition does, say, the Swedish parties of the centre-right or the Republican party of 2008 show “hostility” to immigrants, unless you define opposition to illegal immigration (shared by two thirds of Americans) and to the welfare state as inter-ethnic "hostility". Indeed, that the pro-immigration Swedish centre-right is just as marginalized with third-world immigrants, as is the American right is a rather telling fact.

If you ask Hispanics themselves, it turns out that they are far to the left of American whites regarding economic policy. As I have written, “In the United States, where while only 35% of non-Hispanic whites prefer higher taxes in return for more government services, the figure is 65% for first generation Hispanic immigrants, and 66% for second generation Hispanics.”

This question has nothing to do with the Republican immigration policies (or, say, policing or drug policy), instead directly asking about attitudes regarding fiscal policies. The gap between Hispanics and whites regarding issues relating to the size of government is immense.

When polled, Hispanics are closer to the Democrats regarding public health care and public education than on questions regarding immigration. If Hispanic support for Democrats was "primarily" driven by immigration policies (or some other proxy for inter-ethnic hostility), we would not observe this pattern.

It should also be noted that the countries of origin of Hispanic immigrants, e.g Mexico, Argentina, El Salvador, Peru, Brazil, Bolivia and Venezuela have a long tradition of populism and left wing economic policy. Is this because of GOP “hostility” to illegal immigration? Hardly.

Immigration is a subcomponent of ethnic identity politics, where the left has an inherent advantage. If Hispanics are poorer than whites with worse social outcomes (currently they earn about half much as of whites), they will observe and resent this, and they will believe that the free market is unfair to them.

In addition, the prospect of enacting resource transfers from the majority population, in the form of cash transfers, government services and quotas and preferences, will be a fixed political advantage of the left, as a classically liberal right can never embrace such measures as enthusiastically as the left.

Poor minorities are loyal supporters of the left almost everywhere, including countries such as Sweden where immigration policy has frequently been more generous during right-of-center governments. Between 2000 and 2006, when the Social Democrats were in power, Sweden took an average of 60.000 immigrants per year. After the right took power in 2006, average immigration increased to 100.000 per year. Yet in the 2010 election 77% pf non-European immigrants voted for the left.

In 1986 Republican President Ronald Reagan enacted amnesty to illegal aliens. In the following presidential election, 70% of Hispanics votes for Democrat Dukakis (who got 40% of the white vote). I doubt that Ronald Reagan was somehow showing “hostility” to the millions of illegal Hispanic immigrants he granted amnesty to.

Bryan Caplan likes free markets, and he likes open borders. So he has constructed a story wherein free immigration of unskilled labor can be easily combined with a smaller welfare state. It would be more honest, and more interesting, if Caplan acknowledged that there is no guarantee that the universe is designed in such a way to remove tradeoff for his ideological principles.

3 comments:

  1. What about all of the other things that libertarians should care about, like economic and individual freedom, freedom of the press, corruption, business ethics, civil society?

    ***

    I have two issues with your analysis. You are assuming that the political system will continue to function pretty much the same way, just with stronger left wing parties and that immigrants will continue to serve as mere voting blocs or constituents of these parties.

    The formation of ethnic immigrant parties is a possibility in european multi party systems. This is in fact already happening in some places in Europe on the local level.

    Right now, left wing or center left and green parties are not diverse themselves. The've got some token minorities, ethnic vote hustlers and some unrepresentative hyper-assimilated, highly educated immigrants among their ranks. These few don't challenge the traditions and policies of their parties and don't demand positions of power and jobs that the native party members care about. But that will change down the road.

    This is where my second issue comes in. The problem with OECD data is, that OECD nations are still run by politicians, institutions and parties that are still monoethnic and unaffected by recent immigration.

    Traditional ethnic diversity in Europe is mostly regional. And these regional ethnic minorities or nations frequently enjoy some amount of political and fiscal autonomy.

    ReplyDelete
  2. Thank you so much for addressing Caplan's particularly noxious political propaganda. I had the displeasure of listening to Caplan's smary enthusiasm for greatly accelerating our policy of importing a new low-productivity ethnic underclass on an Econ Talk podcast a while back and it was more than I could stomach.

    In evaluating the costs and benefits of immigration into a democratic welfare state, Caplan absolutely refuses to consider different classes of immigration like skilled versus unskilled and legal versus illegal.

    Worst yet he seems to think that the only cultural difference between the U.S. the countries that supply our illegal immigrants is that we eat different food.

    I especially appreciate your bravery in taking a position that is largely verboten in the academic priesthood. Libertarians are so foolish and so cowardly about veering from the PC dogma that I've stopped calling myself libertarian, lest I be confused with the likes of Caplan.

    When it comes to immigration, libertarians should remember that the much celebrated immigration in the early 20th century is what gave us FDR and the welfare state in the first place. We actually got off easy.

    In 1900 Argentina was one of the wealthiest countries in the world, per capita and waves of immigrants utterly wrecked the political system and the economy while drastically changing the culture. There is something very damaging to the psyche of a nation that experiences a century of decline and people in Argentina consistently poll among the least happy in the world.

    I particularly like the example of Argentina because all of the immigrants were white and at 97% white (CIA factbook) Argentina is probably the whitest country in either North or South America. This deprives Caplan and his ilk from hiding behind insinuations of racism, the perpetual refuge of academic cowards.

    -Mercy

    P.S. Like Caplan, I'm also married to an immigrant, but that doesn't mean my spouse doesn't care about preserving what makes this country attractive to immigrants in the first place.

    ReplyDelete
  3. Thanks for your posts, I am looking forward for future posts. Certainly I have become a big fan of yours and waiting for new posts. Your blogs are like risk free day trading. Please share new post on your blog that would be very helpful for me and other visitors.

    Scott

    ReplyDelete

Google Analytics Alternative